Site hosted by Angelfire.com: Build your free website today!

PAN DISCUSSION GROUP 

Home

*****************************************************

PAN Discussion Group WEDNESDAY May 30th 2007

Subject: Medical Care in The USA

******************************************************

Location:  Irving Park and Lincoln - ish  RSVP for details

Time: 7pm to 10pm - ish

 Bring drinks and snacks to share 

 Thanks to everyone who sent articles

 General:

The articles are the basis for the discussion and reading them helps give us some common ground and focus for the discussion, especially where we would otherwise be ignorant of the issues. The discussions are not intended as debates or arguments, rather they should be a chance to explore ideas and issues in a constructive forum. Feel free to bring along other stuff you've read on this, related subjects or on topics the group might be interested in for future meetings.

 GROUND RULES:

* Temper the urge to speak with the discipline to listen and leave space for others

* Balance the desire to teach with a passion to learn

* Hear what is said and listen for what is meant

* Marry your certainties with others' possibilities

* Reserve judgment until you can claim the understanding we seek

 Any problems let me know...

Colin

tysoe2@yahoo.com 

The Articles:

 First a quick summary from that learned journal Yahoo News

http://news.yahoo.com/s/nm/20070515/us_nm/healthcare_usa_dc

U.S. healthcare expensive, inefficient: report

By Maggie Fox, Health and Science EditorTue May 15, 1:25 AM ET

Americans get the poorest health care and yet pay the most compared to five other rich countries, according to a report released on Tuesday. Germany, Britain, Australia and Canada all provide better care for less money, the Commonwealth Fund report found.

"The U.S. health care system ranks last compared with five other nations on measures of quality, access, efficiency, equity, and outcomes," the non-profit group which studies health care issues said in a statement.

Canada rates second worst out of the five overall. Germany scored highest, followed by Britain, Australia and New Zealand.

"The United States is not getting value for the money that is spent on health care," Commonwealth Fund president Karen Davis said in a telephone interview.

The group has consistently found that the United States, the only one of the six nations that does not provide universal health care, scores more poorly than the others on many measures of health care. Congress, President George W. Bush, many employers and insurers have all agreed in recent months to overhaul the U.S. health care system -- an uncoordinated conglomeration of employer-funded care, private health insurance and government programs.

The current system leaves about 45 million people with no insurance at all, according to U.S. government estimates from 2005, and many studies have shown most of these people do not receive preventive services that not only keep them healthier, but reduce long-term costs.

Davis said the fund's researchers looked at hard data for the report. "It is pretty indisputable that we spend twice what other countries spend on average," she said. Per capita health spending in the United States in 2004 was $6,102, twice that of Germany, which spent $3,005. Canada spent $3,165, New Zealand $2,083 and Australia $2,876, while Britain spent $2,546 per person.

KEY MEASURES

"We focus primarily on measures that are sensitive to medical care making a difference -- infant mortality and healthy lives at age 60," Davis said. "Those are pretty key measures, like how long you live and whether you are going to die before age 75." Measures of other aspects of care such as cataract surgery or hip replacements is harder to come by, she said. They also looked at convenience and again found the United States lacking -- with a few exceptions.

"We include measures such as waiting more than four months for elective, non-emergency surgery. The United States doesn't do as well as Germany but it does a lot better than the other countries on waiting time for surgery," Davis said. "We looked at the time it takes to get in to see your own doctor ... (or) once you go to the emergency room do you sit there for more than two hours, and truthfully, we don't do well on those measures," Davis said. According to the report, 61 percent of U.S. patients said it was somewhat or very difficult to get care on nights or weekends, compared with 25 percent to 59 percent in other countries.  "The area where the U.S. health care system performs best is preventive care, an area that has been monitored closely for over a decade by managed care plans," the report reads.

The United States had the fewest patients -- 84 percent -- reporting that they have a regular doctor.  And U.S. doctors are the least wired, with the lowest percentage using electronic medical records or receiving electronic updates on recommended treatments.

------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

A deeper comparison of  The US with the rest of the world ..

 http://content.healthaffairs.org/cgi/content/full/23/3/10?eaf

 

U.S. Health Care Spending In An International Context

Uwe E. Reinhardt, Peter S. Hussey and Gerard F. Anderson

 Abstract
Using the most recent data on health spending published by the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), we explore reasons why U.S. health spending towers over that of other countries with much older populations. Prominent among the reasons are higher U.S. per capita gross domestic product (GDP) as well as a highly complex and fragmented payment system that weakens the demand side of the health sector and entails high administrative costs. We examine the economic burden that health spending places on the U.S. economy. We comment on attempts by U.S. policy-makers to increase the prices foreign health systems pay for U.S. prescription drugs.


For a brief moment in the early 1990s it seemed that the combination of "managed care" embedded in "managed competition" would allow the United States to keep its annual growth of health care spending roughly in step with the annual growth of gross domestic product (GDP). It was a short-lived illusion. By the turn of the millennium the annual growth in U.S. health spending once again began to exceed the annual growth in the rest of the GDP by ever-larger margins.

In the United States the impact on health spending of managed care and managed competition had been controversial from the start. Skeptics argued that these tools might yield a one-time savings, spread over a few years, but that by themselves they would be unlikely to slow the long-term growth in health spending thereafter.1 It now appears that these analysts were right. In retrospect, and taking a longer-run view, the cost control of the early and mid-1990s merely represents an abnormal period in the history of U.S. health care.

Data for 2001, released by the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), show that over the period 1990–2001 the United States succeeded only in matching the median growth in inflation-adjusted health spending per capita in the other twenty-nine countries included in the OECD database (Exhibit 1Go).2 Viewed in that context, the United States can hardly claim to have found the panacea for cost control during the 1990s.


View this table:
[in this window]
[in a new window]
 

EXHIBIT 1 Health Spending In OECD Countries, 2001

 

 
Furthermore, as can be seen in Exhibit 1Go, U.S. per capita health spending continued to exceed per capita health spending in the other OECD countries, by huge margins, in 2001. After expenditures are converted into purchasing-power parity international dollars (PPP$), Switzerland spent only 68 percent as much on health care per capita in 2001 as the United States.3 Neighboring Canada, with a health care delivery system and medical practice styles fairly similar to those in the United States, spent only 57 percent as much per capita as the United States. PPP-adjusted per capita spending in the median OECD country was only 44 percent of the U.S. level (PPP$2,161).

Finally, the median percentage of GDP absorbed by health care in the non-U.S. OECD countries in 2001 was only 8.3 percent, compared with 13.9 percent in the United States. Although that percentage remained more or less constant during the 1990s, during the previous two decades the average annual growth of health spending exceeded the growth of total GDP by 2.5–3 percent.4 U.S. government actuaries now project that during 2003–2013 U.S. health spending will revert to its traditional, long-term trend. They project the annual growth in U.S. health spending to exceed the annual growth in GDP once again by about two percentage points, and total national health spending to absorb as much as 18.4 percent of U.S. GDP by 2013.5

In this paper we examine data from the OECD database in detail. We begin with a brief review of the factors that can explain the relatively high U.S. spending on health care, drawing on earlier papers on the subject.6 We then discuss international issues in pharmaceutical pricing. Next, we explore the ways that health spending trends might be a burden on the U.S. economy. We conclude that while these trends are not an imminent burden on the macro economy, they will place an increasing burden on the members of lower-income groups even within the coming decade. Furthermore, by 2040 these trends will force the United States to make do with actual reductions in the nonhealth GDP per capita overall. This prospect leads many observers to judge current trends in U.S. health spending "unsustainable" or "unaffordable," although, as we argue further on, these terms are so highly subjective that they lose meaning in this context.

   Factors Driving High U.S. Health Spending

 
GDP per capita. No single factor explains the levels or rates of increase in health spending among industrialized countries.7 However, ability to pay, as measured by GDP per capita, has repeatedly been shown to be one of the most important factors.8 About 90 percent of the observed cross-national variation in health spending across the OECD countries in 2001 can be explained simply by GDP per capita. An estimated bivariate relationship between GDP per capita and per capita health spending predicts a U.S. per capita health spending level of $3,435 for 2001. The actual level, $4,887, is $1,452 or 42 percent higher than the predicted level.9 Both policymakers and clinicians need to examine what other factors can account for that remaining differential.

Distribution of market power and prices. In a previous paper we argued that Americans pay much higher prices for the same health services than citizens in other countries pay.10 There are a number of reasons why this might be so.

First, the distribution of compensation in the United States is wider than in most of the other industrialized countries. The highly trained and highly talented health professionals employed in health care must be recruited from the same talent pool used by other industries offering high compensation, such as law and finance. Because health care is a labor-intensive industry, labor is one factor driving up the cost of producing health care in the United States.

Second, the highly fragmented organization of the financing of health care in the United States serves to allocate relatively greater market power to the supply side of the health system than to the demand side. As we have argued in previous papers, multiple purchasers of care allow U.S. prices to rise above the level attained in other industrialized countries that either endow the demand side of their health systems with strong, monopsonistic (single-buyer) market power (such as the Canadian provincial health plans) or allow multipayer systems to bargain collectively with the providers of health care, sometimes within government-set overall health care budgets (as, for example, in Germany).11

The capacity of health systems. The relatively greater market power on the demand side of health systems in other countries can explain why so many countries allocate a lower fraction of their GDP to health care even though they appear to be more heavily endowed with hospital capacity and health professionals than the United States.12

Many industrialized countries have higher physician- and nurse-to-population ratios than the United States (Exhibit 2Go).13 The supply of U.S. physicians per capita grew only 1 percent per year between 1991 and 2001; only six countries had slower growth rates during this period. A large part of the increase in the U.S. physician supply represents international medical graduates (IMGs), as the capacity of U.S. medical schools has stayed virtually constant since the 1970s.14 The U.S. nurse-to-population ratio (8.1 per 1,000 population) also was below the OECD median (9.0) in 2001. Growth in the supply of nurses was relatively modest in the United States—about 1.3 percent per year—and below the median growth rate for the OECD (1.6 percent).

View this table:
[in this window]
[in a new window]
 

EXHIBIT 2 Number Of Health Professionals And Hospital Beds Per 1,000 Population In OECD Countries, 1991–2001

 

 
Previous comparisons indicated that in recent years the United States has had a relatively low supply of computed tomography (CT) scanners and magnetic resonance imaging (MRI) devices relative to some OECD countries. The United States was an early adopter of these medical technologies and then tended to be relatively well endowed with the new technology by international standards. Ultimately, however, the United States did not acquire as large a supply as Japan and several other countries did.15

Finally, the United States has a relatively small endowment of hospital beds per capita compared with most other OECD countries (Exhibit 2Go). The United States is in the bottom quartile of hospital beds per capita. The decrease in U.S. hospital capacity between 1991 and 2001—0.8 beds per 1,000 population—is at the median for OECD countries with available data.

Administrative complexity and costs. By international standards, the U.S. approach to financing health care is extremely complex. Research suggests that a sizable fraction of higher U.S. health spending, not explainable by higher GDP per capita, can be traced to the higher administrative overhead required by such a complex system.16 To quote economist Henry Aaron on this point: "Like many other observers, I look at the U.S. health care system and see an administrative monstrosity, a truly bizarre mélange of thousands of payers with payment systems that differ for no socially beneficial reason, as well as staggeringly complex public system with mind-boggling administered prices and other rules expressing distinctions that can only be regarded as weird."17

Aaron’s comment was part of his response to a recent paper by Steffie Woolhandler, Terry Campbell, and David Himmelstein, who find that administrative costs for insurers, employers, and the providers of health care in the U.S. health system (not even including the time costs patients bear in choosing health insurance and claiming reimbursement) were "at least" $294.3 billion in 1999, or about 24 percent of total U.S. health spending.18

Aaron’s remarks may leave the impression that public insurance programs are the chief culprits in this "administrative monstrosity." However, as Commonwealth Fund president Karen Davis observed in her recent testimony before Congress, administrative expenses for private insurance in the United States are two-and-one-half times as high as those for public programs.19

Unwillingness to ration health care. A country’s health care system—especially its research and development (R&D) infrastructure—continually gives society the option of purchasing, through health care, additional quality-adjusted life years (QALYs) at increasingly higher prices. Exhibit 3Go illustrates the shape such supply curves are likely to have.


View larger version (13K):
[in this window]
[in a new window]
 

EXHIBIT 3 Hypothetical Supply Of Quality-Adjusted Life Year (QALY) Curve Offered By A Modern Health Care System

 

 
The hypothetical curve in Exhibit 3Go reflects the fact that some relatively low-cost medical interventions can yield additional QALYs at relatively low incremental costs—for example, immunizations or prenatal care. At the other end of the spectrum, however, the health system can wrestle additional life years from nature’s course only at increasingly higher incremental costs. Examples of such high-cost procedures would be diagnostic tests broadly applied to populations with a low incidence of the disease targeted by the test, especially in the presence of many false positives. Heroic medical intervention at life’s beginning or end also falls into the high-cost range of the QALY supply curve.

The thrust of modern cost-effectiveness research—a distinct branch of health services research—is aimed at identifying the approximate shape of this curve for policymakers. In principle, policymakers should use that information to answer two morally troublesome questions faced by every country. First, how far up the QALY supply should the health system go to procure added QALYs? Second, should the maximum price to be paid for added QALYs be uniformly applied to all members of society or be allowed to vary with the individual patient’s ability to pay or with other factors, such as social status?

As Julian Le Grand suggests, the National Institute for Clinical Effectiveness (NICE) established by the Blair government in the United Kingdom appears to be using a cutoff price of £30,000 (about US$53,000 at the current exchange rate) per QALY beyond which treatments should not be publicly funded.20 Above this threshold, U.K. patients with discretionary funds or supplemental private health insurance could procure more costly treatments from the country’s relatively small private health sector. That cutoff price is mentioned also by Nancy Devlin and colleagues, who write that "it is clear from papers presented to NICE’s Annual Public Meeting that £30,000 per QALY has effectively become the benchmark for cost-effectiveness," although they add that "there have been no directions from the Department of Health or the National Assembly for Wales that they consider this to be an appropriate test."21

Policymakers in other countries typically have shied away from setting an explicit cutoff price per QALY (or other measure of outcome) above which collective funds will not be used to purchase additional output from the health sector. Such a pronouncement would undoubtedly be politically controversial and divisive. Instead, countries typically have sought to set that upper limit implicitly, through a mixture of price controls and limits on capacity. If one had to make a rough guess on the implicit prices that health systems are willing to pay for QALYs, the relative overall positions of the United Kingdom, Canada, and the United States in Exhibit 3Go seem plausible, although we make no pretense that the differentials suggested there are accurate. It might be illuminating in future cross-national research to extract through opinion surveys from various stakeholders in health care more explicit notions on the maximum price that should be devoted to wrestling an additional QALY from nature through the health care system.

In the United States neither private health insurers nor the publicly funded Medicare and Medicaid programs appear to observe any explicit guidelines on the maximum price per QALY procured through health care. Two possible exceptions are private health insurance policies that have lifetime upper limits and the Medicare program, which lacks catastrophic benefits. For low-income Americans without health insurance, there may well be much lower, haphazardly imposed, implicit upper limits on the price per QALY that society is willing to pay on their behalf.22 A series of recent reports by the Institute of Medicine (IOM) has documented that uninsured Americans receive less care than insured Americans and that circumstance does affect their health status.23

   The Brewing Battle Over Pharmaceutical Prices

 
Although health care has not traditionally been a focus of U.S.
foreign and trade policy, the relatively high concentration of market power on the demand side of foreign health systems appears to have become a major irritant to U.S. officials, at least with respect to pharmaceutical prices. These officials acknowledge that U.S. prices for pharmaceuticals are high by international standards; however, they accuse foreign governments of keeping those prices artificially and unduly low within their own health systems, thereby beggaring U.S. patients, who now fund the bulk of U.S. pharmaceutical R&D.

In a recent address to pharmaceutical executives, for example, former Food and Drug Administration (FDA) Commissioner Mark McClellan (now head of the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services, or CMS) decried as "unfair" that other nations use market power on the demand side for prescription drugs to obtain lower prices. He was concerned that other countries are shifting the burden of financing the R&D cost of new drugs to the United States. "Some of the world’s richest nations are driving the world’s hardest bargains," he remarked. "For example, many high-income countries regulate their prices by setting them equal to those in other countries that already have rigid price controls. This system is used in Canada, informally in Japan, and in some countries in Europe."24

This concern over unduly low drug prices abroad now finds expression in U.S. trade negotiations with other countries. As the International Herald Tribune recently reported, "In talks over a free-trade agreement with Australia, U.S. officials are pressing the Australian government to water down its system for negotiating the prices it pays for prescription drugs."25 Countries that use price controls to constrain the growth of their health spending can expect to be pressured by the U.S. government to raise the prices their health systems pay for drugs sold by U.S. manufacturers. Countries subjected to these tactics by U.S. trade negotiators may resent this intrusion by the U.S. government into what they may regard as purely domestic health policies.

The emerging posture among U.S. policymakers on drug prices raises a number of questions. First, by what mechanism would higher drug prices paid by foreign health systems for U.S.-manufactured drugs actually translate into lower drug prices for U.S. patients? Or would these price increases merely translate into increased revenues of U.S. manufacturers? Second, how much of the added revenue garnered by U.S. manufacturers from drug price increases abroad would flow through to R&D spending? In 2002 the thirteen largest U.S. pharmaceutical companies allocated their sales revenue to particular objects of expenditures and profits as follows: cost of goods sold, 25.3 percent; selling and administration, 32.8 percent; R&D, 14 percent; taxes, 7.3 percent; and net after-tax profits, 20.6 percent.26 Would added revenues from increased drug prices abroad be similarly allocated? If so, can the U.S. government and U.S. drug manufacturers reasonably expect health systems abroad to underwrite with higher prices outlays by U.S. manufacturers on selling and administration, including the direct-to-consumer (DTC) advertising that is not even permitted in many of these other countries?

Third, would the U.S. government permit other countries’s health systems to use approaches with tiered pricing, such as reference pricing, which can be and has been defended as a market-based approach to drug pricing but is profoundly feared by drug manufacturers in the United States and elsewhere?27 How deeply into other countries’ health policy would U.S. policymakers penetrate to shore up the revenues of U.S. drug manufacturers?

Finally, it is not clear to what extent drug prices in other nations actually are inappropriately low. A recent study by Patricia Danzon and Michael Furukawa suggests that the differential in prices paid for drugs in different countries is smaller than a simple comparison of drug prices might suggest. They argue that simple comparisons of prices for particular drugs can be highly misleading and that such comparisons should be based on broader market baskets of pharmaceutical products sold in the various countries. Furthermore, they argue that such comparisons should be made with PPP dollars rather than at current exchange rates. On that basis, they conclude that "U.S.– foreign differentials for broad baskets of prescription drugs are in line with income [differentials across countries] and [are] smaller for drugs than for other medical services."28

   Health Care In The Macro Economy

 
Health spending and GDP. Health spending is included in the calculation of GDP. If spending on health care increases, other things being equal, then GDP rises, just as it does when there is increased spending on sport-utility vehicles (SUVs) or entertainment, other things being equal.

Other things, however, may not remain equal when one component of GDP grows over time. Under full employment of a country’s real resources, for example, added spending on health care would draw labor and capital away from other sectors of the economy, whose contribution to GDP would then shrink. That displaced contribution would be the opportunity cost of added health spending.

On the other hand, under conditions of pervasive unemployment, added health spending may not need to draw real resources away from other economic activities and GDP; the opportunity costs of added health spending would be low or close to zero. This is an important point during recessions. In a speech before the Commonwealth Club of California in June 2002, for example, President George W. Bush remarked, "Much of the growth we have seen in this quarter is the result of consumer spending, fueled by well-timed tax deductions."29 If one accepts this purely Keynesian strategy of kindling economic growth as appropriate, as evidently the president does, then added health spending, which will create jobs, is a good substitute for tax cuts designed to kindle added consumer spending. The main difference is that added health spending draws added real resources into the production of health care, while tax cuts draw real resources into the production of whatever consumers purchase with their extra disposable income, which may, however, include added production (and jobs) abroad from additional imports purchased by Americans.

Even under conditions of full employment, however, a diversion of real resources from other economic activities to health care might improve economic welfare in society. It would depend on the value of the added health care gained relative to the opportunity costs represented by the value of other output given up. In an efficiently operated economy, the benefit-cost ratios associated with marginal shifts of real resources from any one sector to any other would be the same for all pairs of sectors and would be close to or equal to one.

The fractions of GDP allocated to particular types of output could, of course, vary over time, in accordance with the relative valuations society attaches to particular types of output over time. In other words, the fact that in most industrialized countries health care has absorbed an ever-increasing fraction of GDP while other types of output—for example, agricultural products—have claimed a decreasing share does not by itself imply an excessive allocation of resources to health care.

Exhibit 4Go illustrates this point with the changing distribution of personal spending in key sectors of the U.S. economy.30 In 1970 medical care represented less than one-tenth of U.S. personal consumption spending, the fifth-largest component after food, housing, transportation, and household operation. In that year Americans spent roughly the same portion of their personal consumption on clothing as they did on medical care. Since that time, medical care has been a steadily increasing share of personal consumption. The only other major categories that have grown since 1970 are recreation and personal business (financial services and similar expenses). By 2001 medical care represented 18.2 percent of personal consumption spending and was the largest component. Even so, absolute real spending on every component of personal consumption spending—even food—increased from 1970 to 2001.



View larger version (27K):
[in this window]
[in a new window]
 

EXHIBIT 4 Components Of U.S. Personal Consumption Spending, 1970–2001

 

 
The alleged economic burden of health spending. How serious a problem, if it is one at all, is the inexorable growth of health care as a component of GDP? On this question the responses of policymakers can vary, depending on their political purview. At the local level, policymakers usually give much weight to the employment opportunities offered by a growing health sector, which leads them to resist reductions in or closing of local health care facilities. On the other hand, at the macroeconomic level, policymakers often view growing health spending with alarm, although added consumer spending on other goods and services—on SUVs or entertainment— invariably is viewed as a sign of economic health by both policymakers and the media. What explains these seemingly inconsistent views toward consumer spending?

Singling out health spending as a macroeconomic drag on the economy appears to have two intellectual roots. First, while recent economic studies have shown that in the aggregate, "medical spending as a whole is worth the increased cost of care," the "whole" may hide many individual medical interventions of dubious clinical and economic merit.31 For example, the highly critical analyses of the U.S. health system by the IOM and the recent analyses of geographic variations in per capita Medicare spending by Elliot Fisher and colleagues have contributed to this suspicion.32 Second, there is the view that the long-run historical divergence in the growth rates of health spending and of the rest of GDP cannot be "sustained" over the long run without reducing the availability of all other goods and services. Another way in which it is often expressed is that these increases simply are not "affordable." Unfortunately, words such as "sustainable" and "affordable" are more easily pronounced than defined.

The word sustainable means "able to be maintained," which raises the question what factors would make something not "maintainable." Here a distinction must be made between "economically sustainable" and "politically sustainable." Continuing the Medicare program in the current form into the indefinite future would be economically sustainable, in the sense that it could be accommodated by an ever-growing GDP. The program may not be politically sustainable, however, if the public or its political representatives refused to countenance the higher taxes on the private sector or transfers from other public programs that such a policy would entail. A similar argument, of course, can be made with regard to any other tax-financed programs, including defense, transportation, education, and farm subsidies.

To afford something, according to the dictionary, means that one has "the means for acquiring it without serious inconvenience." Evidently "affordable" is a highly subjective term as well, which should be sparingly used in the context of health care. What, after all, is meant by a "serious inconvenience"?

Given these ambiguities, we do not use either term in what follows and merely explore instead what impact further health spending growth is likely to have on the partitioning of future GDP into health care and non–health care GDP, leaving it to the reader to draw his or her own inferences from that exploration on "sustainability" and "affordability."

It was noted in Exhibit 1Go that during the 1990s real (inflation-adjusted) health spending tended to outpace the growth of GDP in most countries. The median differential in growth rates for the OECD countries was about one percentage point. Historically, that differential has been much higher in the United States. The difference between real per capita health spending and GDP growth averaged 3.4 percentage points during the 1960s, 2.4 during the 1970s, and 3.2 during the 1980s.33 Only in the 1990s was the differential held to 1.0 percentage points, and most of that can be attributed to robust growth in the overall U.S. economy, not lower health spending. Over the entire period 1960–1999 the differential in the United States had been about 2.4 percentage points.34

The CMS actuaries report that the United States as a whole spent an estimated $1.5 trillion on health care in 2003, or 14.9 percent of a GDP of $10.9 trillion.35 They project that by 2013 the United States will spend about $3.36 trillion on health care, or 18.4 percent of a GDP of $18.24 trillion. Stated in constant 2003 dollars and on a per capita basis, the actuaries’ projections imply an average annual growth rate in real per capita GDP of 1.9 percent, while the corresponding growth rate in real per capita health spending is about 3.8 percent.36 It implies a projected growth rate differential of 1.9 percentage points. All of these calculations, of course, are merely conjectures and subject to error.

Although health spending in the amount of $3.36 trillion in 2013 may seem alarming, the nonhealth GDP projected to be available to Americans in that year would still be $5.6 trillion larger than it was in 2003. This implies that in 2003 U.S. dollars, Americans are projected to have 16.4 percent more nonhealth GDP per capita in 2013 than they had in 2003. While nonhealth GDP’s share of total GDP is projected to fall over the decade (from 85.1 percent in 2003 to 81.6 percent in 2013), in absolute real dollars Americans are projected to have more of everything, besides health care. During 1960–1990, when the percentage of GDP spent on health care increased rapidly as well, the absolute amount spent on other goods and services also continued to increase.

As Michael Chernew and colleagues showed in a recent paper, however, this relatively comfortable scenario might not last.37 They calculate that the U.S. economy most probably could absorb a growth rate differential of about one percentage point throughout the next seven decades and still have real nonhealth GDP per capita grow throughout that period. On the other hand, a growth rate differential of two percentage points would keep nonhealth GDP per capita rising until about 2040, after which time it would begin to decline at an ever more rapid rate. All of these calculations, of course, are highly sensitive to assumptions about future overall productivity growth in the economy.

Pricing Low-Income Americans Out Of Health Care Although from a macroeconomic perspective the United States could afford to let health spending grow more rapidly than overall GDP for several decades without depressing aggregate nonhealth GDP, that differential in growth rates can induce severe economic distress at the microeconomic level. To illustrate, consider a private business firm whose line of business and workforce skill mix is such that it can tolerate only a maximum total compensation of $35,000 per worker per year. At higher compensation levels, the firm would lose money on employing such a worker. This assumed total compensation includes the workers’ take-home pay, all withholdings from their paychecks, and all contribution the firm makes to payroll taxes and other fringe benefits, including health insurance. It does not matter how these contributions are divided between employer and employee. The crucial point is that the health insurance premiums paid by or on behalf of these workers must be supported by this total compensation of $35,000 per worker.

If we assume that these workers’ productivity (in terms of physical units of output produced) rises at an average rate of 1.5 percent and that the prices of the firm’s output inflate at the general price inflation in the economy of about 2.5 percent, then one can plausibly assume that the total wage base per worker in this industry will increase at an average annual rate of 4 percent over the next decade, to about $50,000 a decade hence.

According to the most recent employer health benefits survey of the Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation and Health Research and Educational Trust, the total premium for a typical employment-based health insurance policy for a family in 2003 was $8,800, split somehow between employer and employee.38 In the past several years these premiums have been rising at rates much in excess of 10 percent.39 If they grew at a rate of "only" 10 percent for the next decade, the typical family coverage would then cost about $21,000 per year a decade hence, or 42 percent of the total wage base of $50,000 projected for that year. Small changes in the assumed future productivity growth in this firm, product price levels, and health insurance premiums could easily drive the fraction of total compensation absorbed by health insurance over 50 percent. In the end, such a firm would be likely to cease offering its employees health insurance, and the income of these workers would be too small to absorb health insurance premiums in excess of $20,000. They would be likely to join the ranks of the uninsured. This prospect puts U.S. policymakers at a crossroads.

One approach would be to persuade the upper half of families in the nation’s income distribution to help purchase adequate health insurance for families in the lower third. One may call it the "universal health insurance" road. It would, of course, involve added taxes and transfers flowing through government budgets, which would bring with them additional government regulation, especially if the aim were to structure the U.S. health system as a one-tier system in which sick people have roughly the same health care experiences regardless of their own ability to pay.

The alternative option would be to embrace as official policy, both in employment-based health insurance and in public insurance programs, a multi-tier health system in which a person’s health care experience would be allowed to vary by his or her ability to pay for health care. In such a system families in the upper half of the income distribution would have a noticeably superior health care experience than families in the lower half would have. This is certainly already the case for U.S. families with good health insurance and those without it.

The emerging political battle at this crossroads is unlikely to be styled in stark terms such as "rationing by income class" or "one-class" versus "two-class" medicine. Instead, it will be styled as a debate over "market competition versus government regulation"; as a simple, technocratic quest for greater "efficiency"; or as the dubious dichotomy of "rationing versus markets," even though textbooks in economics instruct the reader that market prices are just another way of rationing scarce commodities, on the basis of ability and willingness to pay.40 At its core, then, the debate over health care, in the United States as elsewhere, is less a pure macroeconomic issue than an exercise in the political economy of sharing.

So why does the land of the consumer get the healthcare it gets ?

 http://knowledge.wpcarey.asu.edu/index.cfm?fa=printArticle&ID=1393

 

Consumer preferences and the relationship between health and consumption

In an ideal world, consumers' choices in relation to the incremental costs of producing goods and services would dictate what gets produced, and at what price. Choices should tell us about preferences.

 But, of course, it's not an ideal world and it is harder for analysts to uncover preferences when there are arbitrary, institutionally-imposed, incentives or distorted messages.

 In his keynote presentation at the 18th Annual Health Economics Conference, W. P. Carey Economics Professor Kerry Smith addressed the issue of how to determine whether consumers' health spending choices were the result of institutionally-imposed incentives, misleading messages, or rational behavior. The conference was hosted by the School of Health Management and Policy at the W. P. Carey School of Business

Consumer sovereignty and how decisions are made 

"In many respects, I think that health economics and environmental economics are on the front lines of challenges to consumer sovereignty," Smith. (In economics, consumer sovereignty refers to the idea that consumers know what is best for themselves.) 

Yet when it comes to health and the environment, consumers' behavior seems at odds with this premise –- or at least what some analysts think constitutes rational behavior. "People say they're concerned about health, yet they smoke and they're overweight," Smith said. "People say they're concerned about the environment, but SUVs are everywhere." 

Perhaps distorted information and incentives lead people to walk one way while talking another. "What we see people do is a function of the information that they receive and the incentives that they get," Smith said. "Fortunately some of this landscape is changing. Our messages on the health front are getting better. They've changed over the last 25 years and continue to change." Smith cited a magazine ad from 1945 that read "More Doctors Smoke Camels Than Any Other Cigarette" and Business Week cover from 2007 with a picture of a man smoking a cigarette. The cover admonishes "Get Healthy -- Or Else."

 "As economists, our job is to take those messages and the actual incentives people face and translate them into economic models that allow us to accurately characterize behavior," Smith said. Given the health messages people receive and incentives they face, then, economists can evaluate whether the level of spending on health care is the result of incentives or consistent with what people want.

Building theoretical models 

University of California, Berkeley Economics Professor Charles Jones -- also a presenter at the Health Economics Conference -- and his co-author, Stanford Economics Professor Robert Hall, do just that in a recent paper, "The Value of Life and the Rise in Health Spending," published in February, 2007 in The Quarterly Journal of Economics.   

Smith said that the question implicit in the Jones and Hall article is, "can we rationalize growing expenditures on health? Are they the result of consumer preferences or the incentives they face?" The question is whether, as Jones and Hall suggest, the rising share of GDP that's devoted to health spending is due to consumer preferences favoring health care over consumption as income rises or -- as critics of Jones and Hall suggest -- a result of the inefficient incentive structure of our health system.

 But Jones and Hall are not the only economists to suggest that rising health is important to consumers. University of Chicago economics professors Kevin Murphy and Robert Topel reached a similar conclusion in a recent paper, "The Value of Health and Longevity," published in The Journal of Political Economy.

 In their work, Murphy and Topel found that increases in life expectancy since 1970 due to health progress against heart disease and cancer added $3.2 trillion per year to national wealth -- about half of GDP. "That is staggering," Smith said.

 Linking health and consumption: complementarity

Both analyses share an important assumption: They maintain that an individual's consumption and his health status are complementary goods. If consumption and health are complementary, then as income leads to greater consumption we should expect health expenditures to also rise. (In economics, complementary goods are those that are consumed together -- hamburger patties and buns, for example, or -- as for the Hall and Jones model  -- consumption of ordinary goods and services and the health services we associate with enhancing the quality and length of our lives.)

 Complementarity is a reasonable way to describe the relationship between health and consumption in contributing to a person's well-being. But does this relationship hold indefinitely? The result lead to extreme outcomes, Smith said. Health services would never experience diminishing returns if with every year of exponential increases in consumption the marginal value of an added expenditure on health was higher due to this persistent complementarity. 

In Murphy and Topel's paper, complementarity is evidenced by improvements in the quality of life that enhances the value of improvements in quantity of life -- and vice-versa. In other words, when people have better quality of life, they value additional years of life more. 

 Empirical evidence of complementarity

 Jones and Hall and Murphy and Topel assume that health and consumption display  complementarity over all ranges of consumption and health. Because this assumption is so central to their conclusions, Smith said, empirical evidence is important to substantiate that theory. Smith cited two studies that provide information about the relationship between health and consumption.

 The first study that presents such empirical evidence is a 2006 stated-preference study by University of Oregon Economics Professor Trudy Cameron and UCLA Professor of Public Policy J.R. DeShazo. The study offers individuals a profile of illnesses and asks them to choose the illness they most want to avoid (keeping in mind the annual cost of avoiding that illness).

 Cameron and DeShazo model the survey results taking into account the actual health conditions experienced by their survey respondents. By comparing the illness that they were being asked about hypothetically to conditions they had and were currently experiencing it was possible to gauge how their willingness to spend on activities to prolong life or reduce the risks of poor health related to their current health state.

 The results indicate that individuals who had experienced the illness that was presented to them would be likely to pay more -- nearly double -- to avoid that disease than a healthy person with no prior experience with the illness.

 Their results also indicate that individuals who had not experienced the particular disease that was presented them but were ill with other diseases would pay less to avoid a life-threatening disease presented to them than either the healthy person without prior experience or the person who had experienced the particular disease. 

 "The quality of their lives was lower, so they were less willing to pay to prolong their lives than those with higher qualities of life," Smith said.

 The second set of empirical evidence comes from a  revealed-preference study that Smith conducted with University of Tennessee Assistant Economics Professor Mary Evans based on a panel of older adults interviewed as part of the Health and Retirement Study. Evans and Smith considered the labor market choices of these adults in 1994. 

 Smith said that one could use a person's willingness to accept wage compensation in exchange for increased risk on the job to evaluate the complementarity relationship between  health and consumption. The study revealed that respondents between the ages of 51 and 55 who were in excellent health required twice as high compensation to accept serious risks as those in the same age group with poorer health.

 "There's a 124 percent increase in the value that respondents place on reducing risk if they are in excellent health over if they're not in excellent health," Smith said.  "This is clear evidence of complementarity. Your health affects your valuation of risk."

 As in the Cameron and DeShazo study, the bottom line is that people who are healthy (those who have a high quality of life) are more willing to pay more to avoid serious illness than people who are not healthy (those who don't have a high quality of life).

 But Smith doubts that healthy individuals' willingness to pay to avoid illness will increase without limit as income increases. At some price point individuals will no longer be willing to pay to avoid the “marginal” illness he suggested.

 That question of a limit to complementarity is central to the public policy debate about health spending. Hall and Jones, for example, suggest that health spending will account for 30 percent of GDP by 2050. But Smith wonders if such a high health share is plausible given the other consequences of this large reallocation of resources. Determining whether there is a limit to the consumption/health complementarity, then, is key to determining whether the current increasing level of health spending will be sustained.

 "The question of a limit to complementarity between health and consumption is likely to influence a significant amount of research that we do in health economics. We can only hope to improve our descriptions of people’s preferences through developing a better understanding of how the information and incentives that we provide people influence their choices," Smith said.

Bottom line

 ·        There is theoretical evidence (Jones and Hall and Murphy and Topel) that rising health expenditure as a share of GDP is a rational response to consumer choices.

·        Both arguments assume significant complementarity between consumption and health. In Murphy and Topel complementarity is evidenced by improvements in the quality of life that enhance the value of improvements in the length or quantity of life -- and vice-versa. 

·        In Jones and Hall's work, complementarity is evidenced by increases in consumption enhancing the value of improvements in health.

·        There is empirical evidence demonstrating the link between health status and willingness to pay for health care.

·        The key question to explore further is whether complementarity has a limit or whether health expenditures and consumption will rise together indefinitely as income rises.

 

And what about all that malpractice stuff driving up costs ..

http://www.hsph.harvard.edu/review/review_fall_05/rvwfall05_malpractice.html

Suspecting that 22-year-old Amy had endometriosis, doctors snaked a fiber-optic tube through her navel and into her body to examine her uterus. But something went wrong: the laparoscope pierced her intestine, causing an abdominal infection that forced surgeons to stitch the bowel to a temporary opening, or colostomy, while she healed.

In the United States, Amy might have sued for malpractice, provided that she could find an attorney willing to take on a complicated, costly case that wasn't a sure winner. If the suit ever reached court--malpractice suits typically take three to five years, and most don't get that far--a lay jury might have awarded her millions of dollars, or nothing at all.

But Amy lives in New Zealand, which eliminated "malpractice roulette" 30 years ago. Instead, medical-injury claims are resolved by a government agency through a process akin to workers' compensation. Medical and legal experts, not juries, evaluate claims and compensate patients according to a formula oriented to meeting their practical needs. Within a few months, Amy received $28,000 to cover temporary lost earnings and expenses such as transportation, home help, and child care. In addition, she received free medical and surgical care through New Zealand's government-funded, universal health care system.

"Awards in New Zealand are generally more modest, but they are also fairer and more transparent," says physician-lawyer Marie Bismark, a 2005 Harkness Fellow in Health Care Policy at the Harvard School of Public Health (HSPH) who advises New Zealand's health and disability commissioner. "When I see multimillion-dollar awards for bowel perforations like Amy's in the U.S., I have to wonder whether some of that money might be better spent on improving patient safety, or shared among a greater number of injured patients."

JUSTICE FOR SOME

3 to 4 percent of all episodes of medical treatment in the U.S. result in injuries.

At most 5 percent of all patients injured file a malpractice claim.

Of those patients who file claims:

68 percent see their claims dropped or dismissed

27 percent see their claims settled

4 percent go to trial and lose

1 percent got to trial and win.

Source: Presentation by Lawrence E. Smarr, president of the Physicians Insurers Association of America (PIAA), to the American College of Surgeons on June 23, 2003, drawing from information from the PIAA Data Sharing Project and relating to outcomes of malpractice cases closed in 2002. For details see http://www.facs.org/about/chapters/smart.pdf

Could a system like this work in the U.S., where malpractice litigation is under fire for being slow, costly, and unfair? That's precisely what a trio of HSPH researchers is hoping to find out. They're developing a model "health court" that would replace jury trials, and they hope to see it tested in one or more states within a few years.

"We want to take the best of what we know now and test it against the personal-injury, or 'tort', system in a number of settings," says David Studdert, HSPH associate professor of law and public health. "We think it will show good results, and that people will want to move in that direction."

Leading the team that includes Studdert and colleague Michelle Mello, associate professor of health policy and law, is Troyen Brennan, HSPH professor of law and public health and a physician with Partners Healthcare System in Boston. The three have published numerous analyses of the malpractice system's shortcomings and believe there is much to learn from the experiences of New Zealand, Sweden, and Denmark.

While details vary among countries, the essential components of schemes that use specially trained experts instead of juries are these:

Over the next two years, HSPH's health policy researchers will develop a health court model meant to be compatible with the American health care and legal environment. Thorny questions of cost, constitutionality, jurisdiction, an appeals process, and the mechanics of selecting judges must all be addressed.

The Harvard team is working in partnership with Common Good, a bipartisan coalition that is building political support for pilot tests of a health court model. Recently, bills were introduced in both the Senate and the House of Representatives to authorize funding for pilot projects in several states. Hearings on the proposed legislation are expected later this year.

'Almost Random'
"Justice in health care today is almost random," says Philip K. Howard, the lawyer and author who founded Common Good, based in New York and Washington, D.C. "Most people who are injured get no compensation, and especially in tragic circumstances, doctors who did nothing wrong are sometimes found liable for millions."

Criticism has increased with the rise of the patient-safety movement. The Institute of Medicine report "To Err Is Human" estimates that bad outcomes caused by errors occur in about one percent of U.S. hospitalizations. According to one of its authors, Lucian Leape, an adjunct professor of health policy in the Department of Health Policy and Management at HSPH whose malpractice research in the early 1990s ignited the safety movement, those errors lead to hundreds of thousands of injuries and as many as 98,000 deaths every year.

Yet less than five percent of all injured patients ever seek or receive compensation, Mello says (see box on page 1). Moreover, there's little evidence to support malpractice lawyers' position that they are weeding out bad doctors and saving lives by winning large settlements for patients.

In fact, notes Howard, the tort system perpetuates bad medicine by making doctors fearful of admitting to and addressing their mistakes. "It has infected health care with a debilitating distrust that drives up costs through defensive medicine," he says. A 1992 study estimated that between $5 billion and $15 billion was wasted on tests ordered by physicians seeking to protect themselves against potential lawsuits. And in a survey of 824 Pennsylvania doctors that Studdert published in the New England Journal of Medicine in May, nine out of ten said they "sometimes or often" practiced defensive medicine.

Boston defense attorney George Wakeman, who has defended physicians in malpractice cases for more than 20 years, thinks doctors would welcome health courts. "Even if physicians had a finding go against them, they would feel they had been much better served, because their case had been reviewed by their medical peers," he says.

Health courts would not directly discipline care providers, Mello notes. Instead, their rulings could be transmitted to state licensure boards and professional societies for further action. How this transfer might be accomplished is a matter for study and debate, she says.

Like many malpractice lawyers, Massachusetts malpractice king Andrew Meyer defends the tort mechanism. "It's the worst system in the world, except for all the others," he says, echoing Churchill's famous quip about democratic government. "I have faith in the common sense of a jury of one's peers, as opposed to individuals who fancy themselves experts."

In fact, the proposed elimination of jury trials will likely render health courts unconstitutional, charges Stephanie Mencimer, a contributing editor of The Washington Monthly who writes about malpractice and legal-reform issues. "Lost in all the jury-bashing inherent in the health court proposal is basic American history: A lot of blood has been spilled in this country to secure the right to a jury trial in a civil case--a right guaranteed in the 7th Amendment," Mencimer wrote recently in an online debate with Common Good's Philip Howard.

But supporters point to a number of durable precedents in the U.S.: administrative systems for workers' compensation, Social Security disability insurance, vaccine injury liability, as well as for maritime, tax, and bankruptcy-related matters. Besides, Mello notes, the right to a jury trial is not one most litigants exercise. "Most Americans believe that the jury trial is a profound right that can't be taken away from consumers," she says. "Often overlooked is that 90 to 95 percent of malpractice cases are never heard by a jury."

The Question of Cost
Another controversial issue: Are health courts affordable? Mencimer is skeptical. "Payments would be lower and more predictable than jury awards, but a lot more people would get them," she says. "So doctors' insurance premiums would have to be exponentially higher, or the compensation levels would wind up being too piddling to matter."

To look at just this question, Studdert and Brennan applied a health courts scenario to malpractice-award data in Colorado and Utah from 1992. They compared insurers' total cost of compensating injured patients under two scenarios: current malpractice litigation and a health court model that applied the Swedish avoidability standard. They found that six times as many patients could be compensated by the latter, at roughly the same cost.

But would patients' compensation be "piddling," as Mencimer predicts? In Colorado, a patient could have received payment of all medical expenses, full replacement of lost income, and up to $250,000 in pain and suffering. In Utah, the package would have been similar, except that patients would have recovered only two-thirds of lost wages.

"Mencimer and other critics raise important questions but provide no evidence to back up their assertions," Studdert notes. "That's why we need pilot projects. Let's run them for three or four years and see what they cost."

The avoidability criterion is "a somewhat slippery concept" whose definition varies slightly from one country to another, says Studdert, adding that defining the term for use in a model health court proposal for the U.S. is among the researchers' tasks. In Denmark, he says, "it all boils down to, 'would reasonable specialists have been able to avoid this particular outcome if they had done something differently?'" If so, the injury merits compensation. New Zealand just this year eliminated this hurdle, awarding payments to all injured patients--a truly no-fault arrangement.

Considering Alternatives
Over the past two decades in the U.S., alternatives to litigation have been proposed. In the 1990s, a no-fault compensation system received serious consideration in Utah and Colorado following a crisis caused by soaring malpractice insurance rates. But momentum faded once those rates stabilized.

Florida and Virginia have implemented no-fault schemes in cases of babies born with devastating neurological injuries. In these states, obstetricians and hospitals pay into a fund from which parents can draw compensation if experts determine that their infants' injuries meet certain clinical criteria and were related to the birthing process. There's no need to prove negligence.

Gil Siegal, an Israeli physician, law professor, and research fellow at Harvard Medical School who is studying the Florida and Virginia programs, notes that they represent a limited test of the health court principle, and that feedback on them has been mixed. For one thing, they deal with a very narrow and specific medical condition, and in Virginia, where the program isn't mandatory, many doctors and hospitals don't participate. For another thing, trial lawyers claim the Virginia program isn't fair--too many injured-baby cases are initially rejected without a just and adequate legal process, says Siegal, a consultant on the HSPH project.

Building Political Will
An unusual feature of the project, funded with $1.5 million from the Robert Wood Johnson Foundation, is the partnership between HSPH researchers and Common Good. Pairing the advocacy organization with the Harvard academics was deliberate, according to Nancy Barrand, the RWJF program officer who collaborated with Harvard in proposing the project to the foundation. "Common Good is hoping to pave the way to test this idea, but they can't do it without the development work that Harvard needs to do," she says. "And Harvard isn't going to go forward without the advocacy of Common Good to get political buy-in."

The health court concept has already won bipartisan support from university presidents as well as medical and public health school deans; the Joint Commission on the Accreditation of Healthcare Organizations; high- ranking government officials, including Republicans Newt Gingrich and Senate Leader Republican William Frist; other health care and legal leaders; and editorial writers at the New York Times, Los Angeles Times, and other media outlets. And according to a national survey conducted last spring by Harris Interactive for Common Good, nearly two out of three Americans favor health courts.

Even so, Mello predicts this innovation may be a "hard sell," given trial lawyers' lobbying power and Americans' knee-jerk propensity to sue. Health courts have tended to flourish in countries where health care is publicly funded, litigation is far less common, and people are generally content with less, including modest compensation for personal injury.

Until now, the U.S. has merely tinkered at the margins of malpractice reform. A growing awareness of medical errors has prompted the public to insist on safe and appropriate medical care. When Americans finally become skeptical of the notion that costly battles between lawyers and doctors is the way to better medicine, they just might be ready to give health courts a chance.

In June, the HSPH researchers returned from Denmark, encouraged by what they observed. Says Studdert: "To go where these systems are functioning well despite the difficult and challenging issues--that's very exciting."

"The question is: In two years, are we going to be in a political climate in which people are willing to come to the table?" asks Mello. "I hope so. After all, we need only one state to sign up for a demonstration project to get things going

That’s all folks!

 Colin

**********************************************************************************************************
 

Home