The Shanwei Shootings and China's Situation
By George FriedmanLast week, a group of Chinese villagers
staged a demonstration against a wind-power project near Shanwei, a town in
Guangdong province about 100 miles from Hong Kong. In the first incident,
protesters blocked access to the site of the wind-power generation project.
The next day, Dec. 6, demonstrators returned. According to Chinese official
reports, they were led by three men -- Huang Xijun, Lin Hanru and Huang
Xirang -- and were armed with knives, steel spears, sticks, dynamite and
Molotov cocktails. Members of the local People's Armed Police fired tear gas
at the crowd, hoping to break things up, but the three leaders rallied the
crowd to continue what, depending on who was telling the story, was either a
protest or attack. According to the description of events given by the
Chinese government, the demonstrators started to throw explosives at the
police as night fell. The police opened fire. Official reports said that
three people were killed, eight wounded.
The protests in Shanwei had
gone on for quite a while before coming to a head last week. The land for
the power project was confiscated a few years ago. The farmers who worked
the land were never compensated for their dislocation. They formally
petitioned for their money in 2004 but were ignored. Public demonstrations
began in August 2005, continuing intermittently. With no compensation
forthcoming, the protests escalated and then exploded, with last week's
incident marking the first reported shootings of demonstrators in China by
official security forces since Tiananmen Square in 1989.
The shooting
is new. The pattern is not. There has been intensifying unrest in China over
the past year -- frequently, as in this case, over issues that have been
simmering for years. This has been particularly true for peasants who have
seen their land confiscated by the government for industrial projects. Money
is issued to local officials by state-owned enterprises and other investment
groups to cover the cost of the land. That money passes through the regional
and local bureaucracies. By the time it should reach the owners, there often
is nothing left; it has been stolen by officials at various levels. No one
denies the farmers' claims to the land, but no one acts to compensate them.
The laborers go from being small farmers to being destitute.
This is
a critical process at the heart of Chinese industrialization. The purchase of
land, including forced sale, is considered necessary for Chinese
economic
development. However, Chinese economic development is driven as much by
corruption as by land. The government in Beijing has no particular desire to
see the farmers dispossessed; on the contrary, the money is made available
for delivery to the farmers. But the diversion of funds is hard-wired into
the process. It is one of the primary means for capital formation in China.
One of the paths to entrepreneurship in China is to become a
government official who can use one's public office for personal savings and
networking -- accumulating enough money and useful contacts to move into
business later. With massive expropriations of land over the past decade
designed to facilitate economic growth, the opportunities -- and compulsion
-- to steal money intended for farmers is powerful. In order to hold onto
his job, a government official must maintain a system of relationships with
superiors, colleagues and subordinates. These relationships are based on
money. If the official doesn't find the money to hold his place in the
bureaucracy, he will lose it. Therefore, the diversion of funds is built
into the system.
The Chinese government wants it both ways. On the
one hand, it does not want unrest among farmers. On the other hand, the
Communist Party elite in Beijing live by patronage. They have risen through
the system because of the web of relationships that makes Chinese
industrialization possible. They can, in very specific cases, take action
against cases of corruption. However, a systematic attack on the causes of
corruption is impossible, without a systematic attack on their own
infrastructure.
This is particularly true in rapidly developing
provinces like Guangdong. The interface between the new economy and the old
has become a battlefield. The old economy was land-based: Mao created a
peasant economy that was overlaid by attempts to industrialize. The new
economy regards land as an input into the industrial machine. However, given
the nature of the Chinese political system, the farmers are not simply bought
out -- they are forced off the land. And that can lead to social
explosions.

The
recent events in Shanwei are unique only in that they resulted in gunfire and
death, and because they were brought to light by the anti-Communist media.
After these reports were picked up and widely circulated by the
international media, the government in Beijing acknowledged what had
occurred, adding details that appeared to show that the demonstrators forced
the police into shooting. But later, the government announced that the head
of the police unit involved had been arrested -- which seems to imply that
the story as originally told by the Chinese wasn't altogether accurate. Why
arrest the cop if explosives were being hurled at police?
The
specifics of what happened, of course, have no geopolitical consequence.
What is important is that tensions in China have been rising steadily.
Thousands of demonstrations (74,000, according to figures released last year
by the government) have taken place -- some reportedly violent, if not fatal.
In
one
case earlier this year, residents protesting corruption related to land
seizures took control of their town, forcing the police out. The Chinese
government appeared to capitulate to the demonstrators, giving into their
demands -- but weeks later, those who had participated in the rising were
quietly arrested. In another incident, which also turned deadly,
brute
squads believed to have been hired by local officials and businesses
attacked protesters. There are numerous other examples to draw from.
Beneath the surface, a number of things are taking place. The
Chinese economy has been growing at a frantic pace. This is not necessarily
because the economy is so healthy, nor because many of these industrial
projects make economic sense. In fact, the government in Beijing has been
very clear that the new projects frequently don't make a great deal of
economic sense, and has been trying to curb them (though it does not
necessarily command obedience in every case from provincial or local
governments). On the other hand, China needs to run very hard to stay in
place. Within what we will call the entrepreneurial bureaucracy -- with
pyramiding, undercapitalized, highly leveraged projects being piled one on
top of the other -- new investment projects are needed in order to generate
cash that stabilizes older, failing projects. Slowing down and consolidating
is not easy when there are bank loans coming due and when money has to be
spread around in order to maintain one's position in the system.
That means that aggressive economic growth is needed. It also means
that massive social dislocation -- including theft of land -- is embedded in
the Chinese system. The flashpoint is the interface between the rapidly
spreading industrial plants and the farmers who own the land. The
bureaucratic entrepreneurs need not only the land, but also the money that
legally is due to the farmers.
China is a mass of dispossessed
farmers, urban workers forced into unemployment by the failure of
state-owned enterprises, and party officials who are urgently working to
cash in on their position. It is a country where the banking system has been
saved from collapse by spinning off bad debts -- at least $600 billion worth,
or nearly half the GDP of China -- into holding companies. This maneuver
cleaned up the banks' books and allowed Western banks to purchase shares in
them, shoring them up. But it also left a huge amount of debt that is owed
internally to people who will never see the funds. Imagine the U.S.
savings-and-loan scandal growing to a size that was nearly half of the
national GDP. As it happened, in the United States the federal government
swallowed a great deal of the S&L bad loans -- but in China, these bad loans
would just about wipe out the country's currency reserves, assuming that the
numbers provided by the government are valid.
Under such
circumstances, it is no surprise that Chinese money is leaving the country,
flowing into the safe havens of U.S. T-Bills or offshore mineral deposits.
Moreover, it is not clear that China's economy is continuing to grow.
China's imports of oil have topped out and, by some reports, have started to
decline -- yet the Chinese are continuing to report unabated growth rates.
How can the economy be growing rapidly while oil imports decline? The
country lacks sufficient energy reserves to fuel such growth, nor can that
level of growth be coming from service industries. At any rate, growth rates
do not by themselves connote economic health. The rate of return on capital
is the ultimate measure of economic success. Anyone prepared to lose money
can generate rapid revenue growth. And anyone facing cash-flow crises due to
debt burden knows how easy it is to slip into revenue-growth obsession. The
Chinese certainly have.
There is, therefore, a
tremendous
tension within China's new economy. The root problem is simple: Capital
allocation has been driven by political and social considerations more than
by economic ones. Who gets loans, and at what rates, frequently has been
decided by the borrower's relation to the bureaucracy, not by the economic
merits of the case. As a result, China, as a nation, has made terrible
investments and is trying to make up for it with rapid growth. That is where
things get difficult: As before with Japan and East Asia, the economy is
thrown into a frenzy of growth in efforts to stabilize the system, but that
growth throws off cash that cannot easily be capitalized and therefore is
invested abroad. Meanwhile, bad debts -- stemming from continued investment
into nonviable or unprofitable businesses, for social or political reasons
-- surge, and the government tries to come up with ways to shuffle the debt
around. In other words, the origin of the problem is simple -- but the
evolution of the problem becomes dizzyingly complex.
This leads to
stresses within the advanced economic sector. In China's case, these
manifest as competition between different political factions for access to
the funds needed to maintain their enterprises. But that is nothing compared
to the tension between the new economy and farmers and the unemployed. As the
system tries to stabilize itself, it seeks both to grow and to become more
efficient. As it grows, the farmers are forced to give up their land. And as
it seeks efficiency, industrial workers lose their jobs.
This is an
explosive mix in any country, but particularly so in China, which has a
tradition of revolution and unrest. The idea that the farmers will simply
walk away from their land or that the unemployed will just head back to the
countryside is simplistic. There are massive social movements in play that
combine the two most powerful forces in China: workers and peasants. Mao did
a lot of work with these two groups. Their interests are now converging. The
decisions of the bureaucratic entrepreneurs are now causing serious pain,
which is becoming evident in increasing social unrest. At Shanwei, that
unrest broke into the open, complete with casualties.
The important
thing to note is that both the quantity and intensity of these
confrontations is increasing. While the Western media focus on the outer
shell of China's economic growth -- the side that is visible in Western
hotels throughout major cities -- the Chinese masses are experiencing
simultaneously both the costs of industrialization and the costs of economic
failure. The sum of this equation is unrest. The question is how far the
unrest will go.
At the moment, there does not appear to be any
national organization that speaks for the farmers or unemployed workers. The
risings are local, driven by particular issues, and are not coordinated on
any national scale. The one group that tried to create a national
resistance, Falun Gong, has been marginalized by the Chinese government.
China's security forces are capable, growing and effective. They have
prevented the emergence of any nationalized opposition thus far.
At
the same time, the growth and intensification of unrest is there for anyone
to exploit. It won't go away, because the underlying economic processes
cannot readily be brought under control. In China, as elsewhere, the
leadership cadre of any mass movement has been made up of intellectuals. But
between Tiananmen Square and jobs in Westernized industries, the Chinese
intellectuals have been either cowed or hired. China is now working hard to
keep these flashpoint issues local and to placate localities that reach the
boiling point -- at least until later, when arrests can be made. That is
what they are doing in Shanwei. The process is working. But as the economy
continues to simultaneously grow and worsen, the social unrest will have to
spread.
The discussion about China used to be about "hard" and "soft"
landings -- terms that were confined to economics. The events in Shanwei
raise the same question in another domain, the political. Police shooting
down demonstrators is not an everyday event in China or anywhere else. But
it has happened, and this event didn't just come from nowhere. The question
of soft and hard landings now must be considered more literally than before.
And in China, hard landings over the past couple of centuries have
been bloody affairs indeed.
Send questions or comments on this article to analysis@stratfor.com.